Inequality and the Marriage Crisis
This is coming later than I’d hoped and the world has moved on, but as promised I want to take up the other frequent rebuttal to the much-debated claim
that economic changes can’t explain the two-parent family’s half
century of decline — the argument that it’s relative income, not
absolute income, that matters most to people’s lives and hopes and
aspirations, and therefore the post-1960s increase in income inequality
suffices to explain the social crisis among the working class even if
working-class wages themselves haven’t really fallen.
As far as potential
evidence for this hypothesis goes, here are a couple of the best cases
I’ve seen. (No doubt there are others.) First, there’s this paper
from Melissa Kearney and Phillip Levine, which correlates higher rates
of unwed teenage births to higher inequality across both the United
States and Europe, and suggests that stratification creates a “culture
of despair” among the young and poor that encourages poorer women to
seek validation and even honor through early motherhood rather than work
or advancement. Second, there’s the chart attached to this Andrew Cherlin op-ed (and featured in his —recommended — new book),
which shows not only that the overall marriage rate was lower in the
Gilded Age and in our own high-Gini-coeffiecient era than in the more
income-compressed 1940s and 1950s, but also that the class gap in the
marriage rate shrank as incomes compressed and then widened as the Gini
coefficient rose.
Now here are the various reasons why I’m skeptical. First,
note that Kearney and Levine are looking at early nonmarital
childbearing — births to mothers 19 years old and younger. But the
American teen birth rate, with the exception of a 1980s surge, has
actually been in steep decline from the 1960s to the present, the period of rising inequality that we’re discussing here, for reasons that are debatable and partially mysterious. (Interestingly, Kearney and Levine are also the authors of the paper arguing
that the influence of “16 and Pregnant” may have played a recent role
in this decline, which is one for the “what’s on television matters”
file.) Now: Some of that trend is driven by later marriage and delayed
childbearing; a lot of those teenage parents in the 1950s and 1960s were
young marrieds (and sometimes shotgun marrieds) having their first
kids, which means they wouldn’t be part of the Kearney-Levine sample or
affected by their proposed explanation. But even if you take the
nonmarital teen birth rate, what you’ll see (look at Table 16) is a rise and then a fall between 1970 and the present (even as the U.S. Gini coefficient kept rising through
the 1990s and 2000s) such that the rate today is back where it was in
1975; meanwhile it was the nonmarital birth rate for everybody else
roughly doubled, with larger increases for older demographics. So
whatever the link between inequality and unwed teen childbearing, it
hasn’t manifested itself across the last four decades the way the
specific correlation in their paper would lead to one to expect.
This doesn’t mean the paper is wrong about the basic idea that, ceteris paribus, people with weaker economics prospects and fewer hopes for advancement tend to make different choices around sex and family than do the middle class and affluent. (As the authors note, today the choice that matters most is often whether or not to have an abortion.) But for the sweeping social change we’ve seen since the 1950s — the spread of single-parent families, serial cohabitation and multi-partner fertility out of the underclass and into the working and middle class — to be explained by an increase in inequality-driven socioeconomic despair, you would need evidence that rising inequality is effectively trapping, not just the poorest Americans, but many millions of people making closer to the median income in the kind of no-hope environment that we associate with the deep poverty of the underclass. And since, again, unwed teen births aren’t soaring with the Gini coefficient, this sense of despair would have to be kicking in somewhat later in the life cycle … so you would need to make the case that more and more late twentysomethings and early thirtysomethings are hitting a wall of crushing hopelessness about their future that previous generations never ran into or had to face.
And I just don’t think
the evidence is there. It isn’t visible in trends in socioeconomic
mobility, which is weaker than it should be but which doesn’t show much of a change over the last half-century. And it isn’t really visible in income inequality trends themselves,
which show the upper class pulling away from the 80 percent and
(especially) the 1 percent pulling away from the 99 percent, but which don’t
show a vast, impossible-to-bridge chasm opening between, say, the
fourth quintile and the second. If despair over opportunity were really
driving post-1960s family trends in the lower middle class, you would
expect to see a visible decrease in mobility over that period,
and a wide enough gap between incomes in the lower middle and the upper
middle that someone born to lower middle class parents or starting out
at a low-wage job would have reason to give up hope of ever bringing
home $50,000 a year. But that isn’t what see: That hypothetical worker’s
chances of material advancement may not be what we would want them to
be, but on the best evidence we have they have not declined as income
inequality has climbed.
Similarly, if
inequality were driving stratification which in turn mainly drives
family breakdown, you would expect the three would be very tightly
associated with one another. But in the big mobility study, by Harvard’s Raj Chetty and others, that found that U.S. mobility was stagnant rather than falling, there was a tight correlation
between socioeconomic mobility and intact families … but a much weaker
correlation between mobility and income equality itself. So it’s hard to
see exactly how the more weakly-correlated trend could be the main
driver of two more tightly-correlated trends.
Then I have similar
arrow-of-causation questions about Cherlin’s (very interesting) charts
showing marriage rates converging and diverging by occupation as
inequality diminishes and then increases. My bigger issue with the chart
is that it doesn’t tell us much about family stability, across
classes or in general, prior to the 1950s: It’s true that mid-20th
century America was distinctively marriage-oriented and fecund compared
to some preceding eras, but while those eras had lower marriage rates
they did not have the rates of divorce and single parenthood associated
with the post-sexual revolution landscape. (Also, marriage rates hit a
unique high in the 1950s, but the decline since is now taking us
into uncharted territory rather than just reverting to a mean.) But even
if we just focus on the post-1950s period, Brad Wilcox has pointed out that using Cherlin’s own classifications it looks like both the decline in marriage rates and the class divergence begin in the ’60s, before
the widening of inequality in the 1970s. So interpreted crudely, his
chart could very easily be used to just make the case that the sexual
revolution weakens marriage, and that weakening in turn causes
inequality – rather than inequality itself being the root cause.
This view, that income
inequality really is mostly the result of family instability, is not
without its champions, since the most common measurements of inequality
tend to use household income, which is vulnerable to changes in family
size and composition and stability. (The same holds for measurements of
income volatility, a subject I’ve touched on earlier.) Indeed, you can
find a sweeping version of
this analysis that argues that controlling for household size basically
eliminates the entire Gini-coefficient change since the 1950s … but
people I trust don’t trust the results there. For more restrained takes,
here are two papers — one from the mid-2000s, one from around 2010 —
that tackle the question; both suggest that family fragmentation had a
meaningful effect on household inequality; at the same time, both point
to research suggesting that female workforce participation has reduced
household inequality, possibly offsetting the fragmentation effect.
So some of the discussion turns on whether you think of the decline of
marriage and rising female earnings as a package deal, which is implicit
(at least) in some left-wing and some right-wing analysis, or whether
you think they didn’t have to happen together and don’t need to be permanently conjoined.
That’s a question for
another time, but in closing I want to reach for a little common ground.
The fact of female earnings growth also points to another issue — the
impact of increasing assortative mating (the well-educated marrying the
well-educated) in an era of rising female earnings and attainment, which
probably tends to magnify inequality itself and which is bound up in a larger trend that I’ve written about before: Namely, the growing geographic segregation of the well-educated,
the way that college graduates cluster more and more in specific
regions and cities and neighborhoods than they did a few generations
back.
Of all the mechanisms
through which economic inequality could be shaping working class family
structure and communal life for the worse, this strikes me as the most
plausible. The problem, that is, isn’t that inequality imposes outright
deprivation on the poor or prevents them from ever becoming middle
class; it’s that when the returns to the talented are significantly
higher than for everyone else, it’s much easier and more natural for
well-educated Americans to self-segregate socially, to live and go to
school and (sometimes) go to church in cities and communities that are effectively gated
against anyone whose earnings miss the cut-off for rent, a down
payment, private school, or whatever else you need to flourish. And that
segregation leads, in a hard-to-quantify but somewhat commonsensical
way, to a kind of hoarding of social capital, in which the pool of
potential friends and mentors and significant others and civic leaders
is shallower and less diverse in working class communities than it would
have been in the past, and certain kinds of social examples and
everyday encounters and support structures that kids and families need
are less immediately available than they would be in a society less
efficient in meritocratic sorting than our own.
This problem, as I’ve argued before in the context of the Piketty debate,
isn’t really a 1 percent issue, since the richest 1 percent are always
going to find ways to self-segregate. (The Harvard of the 1950s was not
somehow a middle-class friendly place just because American incomes were
more compressed overall.) Rather, it’s more a problem of what Piketty
calls the “petits rentiers,” the mass upper class, whose interests are opposed to sound public policy
in various ways, but whose increasing self-segregation, in particular,
is effectively underwritten by everything from the tax code to urban
zoning rules to immigration policy. And since that underwriting has
critics on both sides of the partisan divide, notwithstanding all the
right-left divisions on inequality it’s possible to imagine a certain kind of egalitarian agenda taking
shape around anti-rentier reforms — and it’s further possible to hope
that this kind of egalitarianism could, by encouraging a little more
dispersal of talent and social capital, gradually work to counteract the
social and familial crisis further down the education/income ladder.
But to return to my
major theme here: This hope, or the hope involved in any public policy
intervention, only makes sense if it’s tempered by the acknowledgment
that Something Else is also going on.
No comments:
Post a Comment