The Economist explains economics
What is the Nash equilibrium and why does it matter?
This week “The Economist explains” is given over to economics. For
each of six days until Saturday this blog will publish a short explainer
on a seminal idea.
The Economist | 6 Sept. 2016
ECONOMISTS can usually explain the past and sometimes predict the
future—but not without help. One of the most important tools at their
disposal is the Nash equilibrium, named after John Nash, who won a Nobel
prize in 1994 for its discovery. This simple concept helps economists
work out how competing companies set their prices, how governments
should design auctions to squeeze the most from bidders and how to
explain the sometimes self-defeating decisions that groups make. What is
the Nash equilibrium, and why does it matter?
One of the best-known illustrations is the prisoner’s dilemma:
two criminals in separate prison cells face the same offer from the
public prosecutor. If they both confess to a bloody murder, they each
face ten years in jail. If one stays quiet while the other confesses,
then the snitch will get to go free, while the other will face a
lifetime in jail. And if both hold their tongue, then they each face a
minor charge, and only a year in the clink. Collectively, it would be
best for both to keep quiet. But given the set-up, an economist armed
with the concept of the Nash equilibrium would predict the opposite: the
only stable outcome is for both to confess.
In a Nash
equilibrium, every person in a group makes the best decision for
herself, based on what she thinks the others will do. And no-one can do
better by changing strategy: every member of the group is doing as well
as they possibly can. In the case of the prisoners' dilemma, keeping
quiet is never a good idea, whatever the other mobster chooses. Since
one suspect might have spilled the beans, snitching avoids a lifetime in
jail for the other. And if the other does keep quiet, then confessing
sets him free. Applied to the real world, economists use the Nash
equilibrium to predict how companies will respond to their competitors’
prices. Two large companies setting pricing strategies to compete
against each other will probably squeeze customers harder than they
could if they each faced thousands of competitors.
The Nash
equilibrium helps economists understand how decisions that are good for
the individual can be terrible for the group.
This tragedy of the
commons explains why we overfish the seas, and why we emit too much
carbon into the atmosphere. Everyone would be better off if only we
could agree to show some restraint. But given what everyone else is
doing, fishing or gas-guzzling makes individual sense. As well as
explaining doom and gloom, it also helps policymakers come up with
solutions to tricky problems. Armed with the Nash equilibrium, economics
geeks claim to have raised billions for the public purse. In 2000 the
British government used their help to design a special auction that sold
off its 3G mobile-telecoms operating licences for a cool £22.5 billion
($35.4 billion). Their trick was to treat the auction as a game, and
tweak the rules so that the best strategy for bidders was to make
bullish bids (the winning bidders were less than pleased with the
outcome). Today the Nash equilibrium underpins modern microeconomics
(though with some refinements). Given that it promises economists the
power to pick winners and losers, it is easy to see why.
Previously in this seriesMonday: Akerlof's market for lemons
Tuesday: The Stolper-Samuelson theorem
Tuesday: The Stolper-Samuelson theorem
Coming up
Thursday: The Keynesian multiplier
Friday: Minsky's financial cycle
Saturday: The Mundell-Fleming trilemma
Thursday: The Keynesian multiplier
Friday: Minsky's financial cycle
Saturday: The Mundell-Fleming trilemma
Over the past several weeks The Economist has run two-page briefs on six seminal economics ideas. Read the full brief on the Nash equilibrium, or click here to download a PDF containing all six of the articles.
No comments:
Post a Comment